7.23: Export Taxes- Large Country Welfare Effects (2024)

  1. Last updated
  2. Save as PDF
  • Page ID
    41085
    • 7.23: Export Taxes- Large Country Welfare Effects (1)
    • Anonymous
    • LibreTexts

    \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash{#1}}} \)

    \( \newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)

    ( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\)

    \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\)

    \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\)

    \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\)

    \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\)

    \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\)

    \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\)

    \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\vectorA}[1]{\vec{#1}} % arrow\)

    \( \newcommand{\vectorAt}[1]{\vec{\text{#1}}} % arrow\)

    \( \newcommand{\vectorB}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\vectorC}[1]{\textbf{#1}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\vectorD}[1]{\overrightarrow{#1}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\vectorDt}[1]{\overrightarrow{\text{#1}}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\vectE}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash{\mathbf {#1}}}} \)

    \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}}}\)

    \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash{#1}}} \)

    \(\newcommand{\avec}{\mathbf a}\) \(\newcommand{\bvec}{\mathbf b}\) \(\newcommand{\cvec}{\mathbf c}\) \(\newcommand{\dvec}{\mathbf d}\) \(\newcommand{\dtil}{\widetilde{\mathbf d}}\) \(\newcommand{\evec}{\mathbf e}\) \(\newcommand{\fvec}{\mathbf f}\) \(\newcommand{\nvec}{\mathbf n}\) \(\newcommand{\pvec}{\mathbf p}\) \(\newcommand{\qvec}{\mathbf q}\) \(\newcommand{\svec}{\mathbf s}\) \(\newcommand{\tvec}{\mathbf t}\) \(\newcommand{\uvec}{\mathbf u}\) \(\newcommand{\vvec}{\mathbf v}\) \(\newcommand{\wvec}{\mathbf w}\) \(\newcommand{\xvec}{\mathbf x}\) \(\newcommand{\yvec}{\mathbf y}\) \(\newcommand{\zvec}{\mathbf z}\) \(\newcommand{\rvec}{\mathbf r}\) \(\newcommand{\mvec}{\mathbf m}\) \(\newcommand{\zerovec}{\mathbf 0}\) \(\newcommand{\onevec}{\mathbf 1}\) \(\newcommand{\real}{\mathbb R}\) \(\newcommand{\twovec}[2]{\left[\begin{array}{r}#1 \\ #2 \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\ctwovec}[2]{\left[\begin{array}{c}#1 \\ #2 \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\threevec}[3]{\left[\begin{array}{r}#1 \\ #2 \\ #3 \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\cthreevec}[3]{\left[\begin{array}{c}#1 \\ #2 \\ #3 \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\fourvec}[4]{\left[\begin{array}{r}#1 \\ #2 \\ #3 \\ #4 \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\cfourvec}[4]{\left[\begin{array}{c}#1 \\ #2 \\ #3 \\ #4 \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\fivevec}[5]{\left[\begin{array}{r}#1 \\ #2 \\ #3 \\ #4 \\ #5 \\ \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\cfivevec}[5]{\left[\begin{array}{c}#1 \\ #2 \\ #3 \\ #4 \\ #5 \\ \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\mattwo}[4]{\left[\begin{array}{rr}#1 \amp #2 \\ #3 \amp #4 \\ \end{array}\right]}\) \(\newcommand{\laspan}[1]{\text{Span}\{#1\}}\) \(\newcommand{\bcal}{\cal B}\) \(\newcommand{\ccal}{\cal C}\) \(\newcommand{\scal}{\cal S}\) \(\newcommand{\wcal}{\cal W}\) \(\newcommand{\ecal}{\cal E}\) \(\newcommand{\coords}[2]{\left\{#1\right\}_{#2}}\) \(\newcommand{\gray}[1]{\color{gray}{#1}}\) \(\newcommand{\lgray}[1]{\color{lightgray}{#1}}\) \(\newcommand{\rank}{\operatorname{rank}}\) \(\newcommand{\row}{\text{Row}}\) \(\newcommand{\col}{\text{Col}}\) \(\renewcommand{\row}{\text{Row}}\) \(\newcommand{\nul}{\text{Nul}}\) \(\newcommand{\var}{\text{Var}}\) \(\newcommand{\corr}{\text{corr}}\) \(\newcommand{\len}[1]{\left|#1\right|}\) \(\newcommand{\bbar}{\overline{\bvec}}\) \(\newcommand{\bhat}{\widehat{\bvec}}\) \(\newcommand{\bperp}{\bvec^\perp}\) \(\newcommand{\xhat}{\widehat{\xvec}}\) \(\newcommand{\vhat}{\widehat{\vvec}}\) \(\newcommand{\uhat}{\widehat{\uvec}}\) \(\newcommand{\what}{\widehat{\wvec}}\) \(\newcommand{\Sighat}{\widehat{\Sigma}}\) \(\newcommand{\lt}{<}\) \(\newcommand{\gt}{>}\) \(\newcommand{\amp}{&}\) \(\definecolor{fillinmathshade}{gray}{0.9}\)

    Learning Objectives
    1. Use a partial equilibrium diagram to identify the welfare effects of an export tax on producer and consumer groups and the government in the exporting and importing countries.
    2. Calculate the national and world welfare effects of an export tax.

    Suppose that there are only two trading countries: one importing country and one exporting country. The supply and demand curves for the two countries are shown in Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\). \(P_{FT}\) is the free trade equilibrium price. At that price, the excess demand by the importing country equals excess supply by the exporter.

    7.23: Export Taxes- Large Country Welfare Effects (2)

    The quantity of imports and exports is shown as the blue line segment on each country’s graph (the horizontal distance between the supply and demand curves at the free trade price). When a large exporting country implements an export tax, it will cause a decrease in the price of the good on the domestic market and an increase in the price in the rest of the world (RoW). Suppose after the tax, the price in the importing country rises to \(P_T^{IM}\) and the price in the exporting country falls to \(P_T^{EX}\). If the tax is a specific tax, then the tax rate would be \(T = P_T^{IM} − P_T^{EX}\), equal to the length of the green line segment in Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\). If the tax were an ad valorem tax, then the tax rate would be given by

    \[ T = \frac{P_T^{IM}}{P_T^{EX}} − 1 \nonumber .\]

    Table \(\PageIndex{1}\) provides a summary of the direction and magnitude of the welfare effects to producers, consumers, and the governments in the importing and exporting countries. The aggregate national welfare effects and the world welfare effects are also shown.

    Table \(\PageIndex{1}\): Welfare Effects of an Export Tax
    Importing Country Exporting Country
    Consumer Surplus − (A + B + C + D) + e
    Producer Surplus + A − (e + f + g + h)
    Govt. Revenue 0 + (c + g)
    National Welfare − (B + C + D) + c − (f + h)
    World Welfare − (B + D) − (f + h)

    Refer to Table \(\PageIndex{1}\) and Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\) to see how the magnitudes of the changes are represented.

    Export tax effects on the exporting country’s consumers. Consumers of the product in the exporting country experience an increase in well-being as a result of the export tax. The decrease in their domestic price raises the amount of consumer surplus in the market.

    Export tax effects on the exporting country’s producers. Producers in the exporting country experience a decrease in well-being as a result of the tax. The decrease in the price of their product in their own market decreases producer surplus in the industry. The price decline also induces a decrease in output, a decrease in employment, and a decrease in profit, payments, or both to fixed costs.

    Export tax effects on the exporting country’s government. The government receives tax revenue as a result of the export tax. Who benefits from the revenue depends on how the government spends it. Typically, the revenue is simply included as part of the general funds collected by the government from various sources. In this case, it is impossible to identify precisely who benefits. However, these funds help support many government spending programs, which presumably help either most people in the country, as is the case with public goods, or certain worthy groups. Thus someone within the country is the likely recipient of these benefits.

    Export tax effects on the exporting country. The aggregate welfare effect for the country is found by summing the gains and losses to consumers and producers. The net effect consists of three components: a positive terms of trade effect (\(c\)), a negative consumption distortion (\(f\)), and a negative production distortion (\(h\)).

    Because there are both positive and negative elements, the net national welfare effect can be either positive or negative. The interesting result, however, is that it can be positive. This means that an export tax implemented by a large exporting country may raise national welfare.

    Generally speaking, the following are true:

    1. Whenever a large country implements a small export tax, it will raise national welfare.
    2. If the tax is set too high, national welfare will fall.
    3. There will be a positive optimal export tax that will maximize national welfare.

    However, it is also important to note that not everyone’s welfare rises when there is an increase in national welfare. Instead, there is a redistribution of income. Producers of the product and recipients of government spending will benefit, but consumers will lose. A national welfare increase, then, means that the sum of the gains exceeds the sum of the losses across all individuals in the economy. Economists generally argue that, in this case, compensation from winners to losers can potentially alleviate the redistribution problem.

    Export tax effects on the importing country’s consumers. Consumers of the product in the importing country suffer a reduction in well-being as a result of the export tax. The increase in the price of both imported goods and the domestic substitutes reduces the amount of consumer surplus in the market.

    Export tax effects on the importing country’s producers. Producers in the importing country experience an increase in well-being as a result of the export tax. The increase in the price of their product on the domestic market increases producer surplus in the industry. The price increase also induces an increase in the output of existing firms (and perhaps the addition of new firms), an increase in employment, and an increase in profit, payments, or both to fixed costs.

    Export tax effects on the importing country’s government. There is no effect on the importing country’s government revenue as a result of the exporter’s tax.

    Export tax effects on the importing country. The aggregate welfare effect for the country is found by summing the gains and losses to consumers, producers, and the government. The net effect consists of three components: a negative terms of trade effect (\(C\)), a negative production distortion (\(B\)), and a negative consumption distortion (\(D\)).

    Since all three components are negative, the export tax must result in a reduction in national welfare for the importing country. However, it is important to note that a redistribution of income occurs—that is, some groups gain while others lose. In this case, the sum of the losses exceeds the sum of the gains.

    Export tax effects on world welfare. The effect on world welfare is found by summing the national welfare effects on the importing and exporting countries. By noting that the terms of trade gain to the exporter is equal to the terms of trade loss to the importer, the world welfare effect reduces to four components: the importer’s negative production distortion (\(B\)), the importer’s negative consumption distortion (\(D\)), the exporter’s negative consumption distortion (\(f\)), and the exporter’s negative production distortion (\(h\)). Since each of these is negative, the world welfare effect of the export tax is negative. The sum of the losses in the world exceeds the sum of the gains. In other words, we can say that an export tax results in a reduction in world production and consumption efficiency.

    Key Takeaways

    • An export tax raises consumer surplus and lowers producer surplus in the exporter market.
    • An export tax lowers producer surplus in the export market and raises it in the import country market.
    • National welfare may rise or fall when a large country implements an export tax.
    • For any country that is large in an export product, there is a positive optimal export tax.
    • National welfare in the importing country falls when a large exporting country implements an export tax.
    • An export tax of any size will reduce world production and consumption efficiency and thus cause world welfare to fall.
    Exercise \(\PageIndex{1}\)
    1. Suppose there are two large countries, the United States and China. Assume that both countries produce and consume clothing. The United States imports clothing from China. Consider the trade policy action listed along the top row of the table below. In the boxes, indicate the effect of the policy on the variables listed in the first column. Use a partial equilibrium, perfect competition model to determine the answers. You do not need to show your work. Use the following notation:

      + the variable increases

      the variable decreases

      0 the variable does not change

      A the variable change is ambiguous (i.e., it may rise, it may fall)

    Table \(\PageIndex{2}\): Effects of an Export Tax
    Chinese Implementation of an Export Tax
    U.S. Domestic Consumer Price
    U.S. Domestic Consumer Welfare
    U.S. Domestic Producer Welfare
    U.S. National Welfare
    Chinese Producer Welfare
    Chinese Consumer Welfare
    Chinese National Welfare
    7.23: Export Taxes- Large Country Welfare Effects (2024)

    FAQs

    7.23: Export Taxes- Large Country Welfare Effects? ›

    For any country that is large in an export product, there is a positive optimal export tax. National welfare in the importing country falls when a large exporting country implements an export tax. An export tax of any size will reduce world production and consumption efficiency and thus cause world welfare to fall.

    How does a large country tariff affect welfare? ›

    2) the higher the tariff is set, the larger will be the loss in national welfare. 3) the tariff causes a redistribution of income. Producers and the recipients of government spending gain, while consumers lose.

    What are the welfare effects of export subsidies? ›

    An export subsidy raises producer surplus in the export market and lowers it in the import country market. National welfare falls when a large country implements an export subsidy. National welfare in the importing country rises when a large exporting country implements an export subsidy.

    How free trade affects welfare in an exporting country? ›

    In an exporting country, free trade enhances total welfare by causing an increase in producer surplus. Even though the consumer surplus might decrease due to increase in domestic price, the total welfare still increases as the gain in producer surplus outweighs the loss in consumer surplus.

    How does an export tax affect domestic prices? ›

    Key Takeaways

    An export tax will lower the domestic price and, in the case of a large country, raise the foreign price. An export tax will decrease the quantity of exports. The export tax will drive a price wedge, equal to the tax rate, between the domestic price and the foreign price of the product.

    Why do tariffs cause welfare loss? ›

    The higher the tariff is set, the larger will be the loss in national welfare. The tariff causes a redistribution of income. Producers and the recipients of government spending gain, while consumers lose.

    How does welfare affect the economy? ›

    In the strictest economic sense, the positive effects of government tend to reduce the costs of producing goods and services, thereby raising output and lowering prices. This increases the sum total of what economists call consumer and producer surplus.

    Who benefits from export subsidies? ›

    Export subsidies allow domestic firms to sell their products abroad at a lower price than they could otherwise, at the expense of the domestic taxpayer. Export subsidies benefit domestic firms that receive subsidies and typically also lead to a decrease in the price that domestic consumers face.

    Why are export subsidies harmful? ›

    Producers in the importing country suffer a decrease in well-being as a result of the export subsidy. The decrease in the price of their product on the domestic market reduces producer surplus in the industry.

    Why does subsidy create welfare loss? ›

    The cost of the subsidy is the responsibility of the government. The cost of providing subsidies is higher than the total gain received by both producers and consumers. This causes inefficiencies in the market and can cause deadweight loss.

    How does trade affect the welfare of a country? ›

    International trade tends to reduce the prices of consumption goods, creating welfare gains for consumers in importing countries. Welfare gains through reduced costs of consumption may be larger than gains or losses through income changes.

    Does free trade benefit the poor? ›

    Not all countries have benefited equally, but overall, trade has generated unprecedented prosperity, helping to lift some 1 billion people out of poverty in recent decades.

    How do exports affect a country? ›

    Exports drive economic growth, create better jobs, and generate foreign exchange earnings. One determinant of export competitiveness is the real effective exchange rate (REER), which measures the value of a currency relative to a basket of other major currencies, adjusted for the effects of domestic inflation.

    Does the US have export tax? ›

    Export Taxes, Charges & Levies

    The U.S. Constitution (Article 1, Section 9) prohibits export taxes.

    What is a tax on exports called? ›

    A tariff is a tax imposed by the government of a country or by a supranational union on imports or exports of goods.

    How does export subsidy affect price? ›

    An export subsidy will raise the domestic price and, in the case of a large country, reduce the foreign price. An export subsidy will increase the quantity of exports. The export subsidy will drive a price wedge, equal to the subsidy value, between the foreign price and the domestic price of the product.

    What impact does the tariff have on the overall welfare of the United States? ›

    Historical evidence shows tariffs raise prices and reduce available quantities of goods and services for U.S. businesses and consumers, which results in lower income, reduced employment, and lower economic output.

    What is a tariff that maximises a country's welfare? ›

    Generally, the optimal tariff is defined as the rate that unilaterally maximizes a country's welfare and is given by the inverse elasticity of foreign export supply, as determined by optimal monopsony pricing.

    Why are the welfare implications of tariffs and quotas different? ›

    Since the domestic price rises more with the quota in place than with the tariff, domestic producers will enjoy a larger supply and consequently a higher level of producer surplus (not shown). Thus the quota is more protective than a tariff in the face of an increase in domestic demand.

    References

    Top Articles
    Latest Posts
    Article information

    Author: Corie Satterfield

    Last Updated:

    Views: 5942

    Rating: 4.1 / 5 (62 voted)

    Reviews: 93% of readers found this page helpful

    Author information

    Name: Corie Satterfield

    Birthday: 1992-08-19

    Address: 850 Benjamin Bridge, Dickinsonchester, CO 68572-0542

    Phone: +26813599986666

    Job: Sales Manager

    Hobby: Table tennis, Soapmaking, Flower arranging, amateur radio, Rock climbing, scrapbook, Horseback riding

    Introduction: My name is Corie Satterfield, I am a fancy, perfect, spotless, quaint, fantastic, funny, lucky person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.